Summary, Judgment

Citation Rankings and the Human Touch

Legal ScholarshipWilliam Baude

I was pondering Adam’s post last Friday about measurement error in law school rankings and then I thought about his posts earlier in the week about human v. computer judges and referees. I wonder if those latter posts provide the best approach to the citation/rankings problem.

Given the imperfections and transparency of citation rankings, they will be gamed in troubling ways. But they still provide important objective evidence that is missing from the current rankings system. Maybe the solution is this: Give the faculty citation counts to some humans, and ask them to use the citation counts to decide scholarly ranking. We could do this with the current survey group for scholarly reputation at US News, or we could do it with a different group of people if we trusted them more for some reason.

The advantages are obvious. The human beings could average, generalize, or combine across multiple rankings systems, and could take into account . They could make some of the tradeoffs Adam describes between junior and senior faculty. And they’d make it harder to game the rankings, because they’d be able to adjust for apparently strategic behavior.

Of course, the problem is that the humans probably wouldn’t be objective enough, and that plenty of humans probably don’t agree that citation counts are all that relevant to scholarly quality, so they might refuse to cooperate in the project. Still, just like asking judges to use data to assign sentences, it might be the best we can do.

Citation Rankings and Measurement Error

Legal ScholarshipAdam Chilton

There’s been a lot of recent debate about ranking law schools based on their faculties’ citations. The U.S. News and World Report has announced plans to incorporate citations into their overall ranking, and Paul Heald and Ted Sichelman have just released a new paper providing exactly that kind of ranking.

Both of these rankings rely on citation counts from HeinOnline. (note: Heald and Sichelman also use SSRN downloads in their rankings.) As many have pointed out, relying on HeinOnline does not measure all of law professors’ citations. Instead, it measures citations to articles published in HeinOnline by other articles published in HeinOnline. If an article published by the Fancy Law Review is cited 100 times by articles published by the Prestigious Law Journal, this isn’t a problem. HeinOnline would pick up all 100 citations. And because most law professors publish most of their scholarship in law reviews carried by HeinOnline, this isn’t a problem most of the time.

But it is a problem some of the time. For instance, if a law professor publishes a book that receives 100 citations, HeinOnline would not pick up any of them. So law schools that have relatively more professors writing books are going to be lower ranked than they should be just because of how the citations are measured for the new rankings. In other words, the proposed new rankings have measurement error.

Of course, measurement error is a reality for anyone working with data, and normally researchers typically don’t get bent out of shape about it. This is because measurement error that is random might lead to distortions, but it’s not going to lead to systematic problems. And when the measurement error is non-random, researchers can just explain to readers the ways that the error is going to bias their results.

But there are a lot of researchers getting bent out of shape about the measurement error in the potential U.S. News and World Report rankings. And I’m one of them. This is because non-random measurement error in rankings creates the potential for gamesmanship. If rankings systematically undercount the work of people that publish in books or in journals that are not indexed by HeinOnline, there will be less of a market to hire these scholars.

This problem is exacerbated by the fact that so many aspects of U.S. News and World Report rankings are extremely sticky. Law school deans can’t snap their fingers and change the median LSAT scores and GPAs of the students that attend their schols. These things move very slowly over time. But they can try to hire scholars with more HeinOnline citations at the margins. The result is that non-random measurement errors in rankings will transalte into distortions of the academic labor market. This will in turn distort our core mission: the production and dissemination of knowledge.

If you care about the ranking debates, Jonathan Masur and I recently posted a short paper on SSRN where we explain this concern and lay out a few more. You should also check out Paul and Ted’s own paper where they explain the numerous steps they’ve already taken to reduce measurement error, and laid our their plans to reduce it even further in the near future. And, although I’ve got concerns about current measurement error in citation rankings, I want to end by saying Paul and Ted are being extremely thoughtful about how to produce rankings as transparently and accurately as possible.

The Market for FedSoc

Legal ProfessionAdam Chilton

Will’s post arguing that the Federalist Society is a network reminds me of a long running debate about why there isn’t a liberal network of lawyers of similar stature. Sure, most law schools have American Constitution Society chapters; but it’s common to hear liberal students lament that joining the ACS isn’t even a path to getting a good fed courts outline, that alone a good clerkship. FedSoc, on the other hand, has always had the well-earned reputation of being extremely effective at opening doors for its members. (At least, that’s the impression from the outside—I’m not a member.)

What explains the difference?

In an article published in Politico earlier this year, Evan Mandery presented the standard explanation of why the FedSoc is more influential than the ACS. Mandery explains that the FedSoc has three advantages over the ACS: (1) it is older, (2) advances an agenda more appealing to rich donors, and (3) has a unifying ideological commitment (originalism) that brings conservatives together.

These arguments all miss the mark. Simply put, there is a market for FedSoc; there isn’t a market for a liberal equivalent.

The reason for this discrepancy is that the legal profession is overwhelmingly liberal. In The Political Ideologies of American Lawyers, my collaborators and I find that over 60 percent of lawyers are liberal. And our subsequent research on law clerks and law professors suggests that more like 75 to 85 percent of elite lawyers are liberal.

The result of this ideological skew in the profession is that anyone hiring lawyers without respect to ideology is going to hire liberals most of the time. This means that people trying to hire for ideological reasons are going to make a lot of “mistakes” if they hire without knowing the candidates ideology. Additionally, the people that are trying to hire for ideological reasons—e.g., the people in charge of selecting political appointees or picking new judges—know perfectly well that lawyers are smart enough to be coy about their ideological commitments when good opportunities depend on coming off as conservative for a short period.

So how can people trying to hire conservatives make sure they don’t accidentally give good jobs to liberal lawyers? Make conservative lawyers send a costly signal that demonstrates their ideological bonafides. Joining FedSoc and attending talks, debates, and social events for years is that costly signal. There was a demand for providing that signal, and the FedSoc met it.

Liberal decision-makers don’t need to rely on the same kind of costly signals when hiring; they can just assume lawyers are liberal and be right most of the time. And they especially don’t need to bother with costly signals once conservatives are taking on the heavy lifting of doing the ideological sorting. Want to hire a liberal law student as your law clerk? Just make sure you don’t hire someone in FedSoc.

So any explanation for why ACS is less influential than FedSoc that focuses on why it is tough for liberals to organize misses the point. The difference in influence isn’t because liberals can’t get their act together; it exists because they don’t need to.

FedSoc is a They, not an It

Legal ProfessionWilliam Baude

The Federalist Society has been in the news (and in my Twitter feed) a lot lately, as people criticize both things that happened at a national convention last week, and things that have been said and done by a couple of its officials, especially Leonard Leo and Steven Calabresi.

This has led to claims that the Society is in fact a partisan organization because of its supposed role in picking judges, to calls that the organization disavow or denounce various things, and to arguments that members of the society have some moral culpability for what other members of the society do.

I am a member of the Federalist Society, but I don’t see things this way and thought I’d try to explain why. As I see it, the Federalist Society is essentially a network that connects thousands of scholars, students, and lawyers. There is obviously some intellectual valence to that network — it is not a random network — but it’s usually a mistake to discuss the network as a collective noun.

Thus, I don’t think it’s right to say that the Federalist Society picks judges. Some judges have been members of the Federalist Society, and so have some people who participated in the selection process. And sharing a network may well make some of those judges more likely to be picked by others in the network. (This is not going to happen to me, to be clear.) But the society doesn’t do anything. Individuals like Leonard Leo and Don McGahn do.

Similarly, I think it’s a mistake to expect the Federalist Society to take official positions beyond, perhaps, its relatively open-ended mission statement. Because the Society is not a legislative, adjudicative, or deliberative body it doesn’t really have a mechanism for taking positions. The positions are held by members of the network. And for the same reason, the fact that one member of the Society, or even an official of the society, has taken a position doesn’t attribute it to the others or to the group.

Finally there is the question of collective responsibility. Unlike the previous two points, I don’t think we can dismiss that out of hand. Maybe there is some kind of collective responsibility to abandon a network or group if you disagree with enough people in the group over enough sufficiently profound issues. Or maybe there is at least a duty to publicly comment on the behavior of other members of the group. But I find thinking of the group as a network helpful in framing these questions. By being part of a network the main thing one is offering is not political power or official endorsement, but one’s own willingness to freely associate.

Agreed, Some Law Professors are Trying to Ruin Sports

Adam Chilton

I agree with Will that consistency in refereeing is a good thing. It’s infuriating to see a home team get nonsense calls when you’re routing for the road team.

But consistency is just one goal that sports leagues are trying to maximize; they are, and should, also be trying to maximize entertainment value. if getting every call right requires stopping games to view every play in slow motion from angles that the refs couldn’t see, at some point it’s just not worth it. If the games are too long and boring, they aren’t worth watching. Leagues know full well that balancing these competing goals is a reality they have no choice but to deal with.

The exact same thing is true in adjudication. It’s important to try and be consistent, we should be outraged when there is overt bias for one group at the expense of another, and we shouldn’t ignore clear evidence of violations (at least, most of the time).

But the judicial system is designed to promote values other than just consistency. We do, and should, care about administrative costs and social consequences when making trade offs about how to manage cases. The Stevenson and Doleac paper I blogged about yesterday suggests that judges understand this the same way that the NBA does.

How Being a Law Professor Ruined Watching Professional Sports for Me

Legal ScholarshipWilliam Baude

Adam’s post about the differences between umpires and referees reminds me of a provocative article by Mitch Berman, “Let ‘em Play” A Study in the Jurisprudence of Sport, as well as these two recent blog posts by Dave Pozen, What Are The Rules of Soccer?, and The Rulification of Penalty Kicks. These pieces all explore the gap between the “law in the books” and the “law in action” in certain professional sports. Though the rules don’t say so, many of us expect the officials to systematically deviate from or underenforce the rules under certain conditions. The analogy to law is natural.

I hate to be a spoilsport, but reading these articles helped me understand what I always found so frustrating about watching, say, the NBA finals. I love basketball, and I live in Chicago, but I still think Michael Jordan should have been held to the same number of steps as everybody else on the court. And I don’t like watching the rules get suspended during the tense final quarter. I think we all agree that the players, not the refs, should be the center of the action during the climax of a game. But in my view by deviating from the duly promulgated rules, even to avoid enforcing them, the refs make their own judgment all too central.

Of course, these views probably will not surprise people who know me, since I am a formalist when it comes to judicial interpretation too. And it seems like I’m in a decided minority. But we shouldn’t take the system of referee discretion for granted.

Judges as Referees

Legal ScholarshipAdam Chilton

Several recent papers have found that algorithms are better at predicting human behavior than judges. In one high profile example, Kleinberg et al. used an algorithm to re-evaluate decisions to grant defendants pre-trial release made by judges in New York City from 2008 to 2013. They showed that an algorithm given variables about “characteristics of the defendant’s current case, their prior criminal record, and age (but not other demographic features like race, ethnicity, or gender)” could dramatically out-perform the actual decisions made by judges. As the authors put it, relying on their algorithm could have produced “crime reductions up to 24.7% with no change in jailing rates, or jailing rate reductions up to 41.9% with no increase in crime rates.” 

Their finding is sufficiently thought provoking that Malcom Gladwell’s used it as a motivating example for his new book, Talking to Strangers. The relevance to Gladwell’s argument is that the judges have access to all the information the researcher input into the algorithm, but they also are able to look the defendant in the eye when assessing their character. But even though the judges have access to more information, the humans are just systematically worse at decisionmaking than computers.

This pessimistic evidence about the quality of judicial decisionmaking reminds me of John Robert’s analogy of judges as umpires. If what we are after is calling balls and strikes, it can now be done more accurately, quickly, and cheaply by computers than umpires.

But a paper released yesterday suggests that maybe judges are better thought of as referees than umpires. Megan Stevenson and Jennifer Doleac’s paper examines how judges in Virginia that were given algorithmic risk assessment scores changed the way they made sentencing decisions. They found that judges’ decisions were influenced by the information: judges gave defendants with higher risk scores longer sentences and defendants with lower risk scores shorter sentences.

However, the judges’ deviated from the risk scores in an important way. Despite high risks of recidivism, the judges systematically gave young defendants more lenient sentences. This deviation leads Stevenson and Doleac to persuasively conclude that the judges’ have goals other than just predicting recidivism in mind when they are making predictions.

This makes judges seem more like basketball referees than baseball umpires. When refs are calling a basketball game, most fans are open to the idea that the refs might call the game differently depending on the circumstances. When the stakes are high—at the end of the game, in the playoffs—we’re often cool with the umpires giving the players more leeway. If this is the right analogy, maybe it’s a little unfair to say that judges aren’t doing a great job of calling balls and strikes when they are actually playing a different game.

What is this?

Adam and Will

Once upon a time, the internet was saturated with law blogs. A lot of these dried up for one reason or another and much legal commentary has moved to Twitter and other social media sites. But we think law blogging remains useful and that the internet could use more of it.

We intend to use this blog to comment on three major topics -- legal developments, legal scholarship, and the legal profession. That will include some of our own scholarly interests, as well as law school and lots of other things.

We are friends and colleagues at the University of Chicago, so we have plenty in common, but we also have very different scholarly specialties and methodologies, so we will likely have some things we disagree about as well.

Watch this space for new posts every week.